Showing posts sorted by date for query school choice. Sort by relevance Show all posts
Showing posts sorted by date for query school choice. Sort by relevance Show all posts

Tuesday, December 26, 2023

Market Design in El Mercurio--Chile's oldest newspaper

Last Tuesday, in Chile I was interviewed by Eduardo Olivares, the editor for Economics and Business of El Mercurio,  which published the interview yesterday. We talked for an hour about market design generally, about how markets work when they're working well or working badly, and we spoke about school choice (where Chile is a leader) and transplantation (where it is not). The interview is behind a paywall, but below are some extracts (retranslated back into English via Google Translate).

On markets generally:

—Many people ask that “markets be free,” as has recently happened in Argentina. Should they be free?

“That's a complicated question. Markets should be free to function well, but they need conditions that allow them to function well. Having a free market does not necessarily mean a market without rules. A wheel can spin freely because it has a well-greased axle and bearings. A wheel by itself cannot turn very well, and the same goes for the market.”

—Who puts the oil in the wheel gears?

“That's the job of market design. Part of what makes markets work well are good market rules. The government has a role in regulating markets, concerning property rights and things like that. But on another level, entrepreneurs do things. Here in Santiago I [can]... call an Uber using the same app and rules I use in California. Uber is a marketplace for passengers and drivers. The rules can be made by both private organizations and the government.”

On prices:

—Do prices matter?

"A lot. “Prices are important to help allocate scarce resources, but also to make them less scarce.”

...

—When do they not matter?

“Let me start with when they matter a lot: in commodity markets. If you want to buy commodities, price is really the only thing that's happening. But when 'El Mercurio' wants to hire journalists, it doesn't limit itself to offering a salary: it wants it to be a good job, with special reporters. Price is important, but in other markets other things are also important. When you get a new job, the first question your friends ask you is not what the salary is, but who you work for.”

On school choice:

“Most markets are not commodity markets... In some markets we don't like prices to work at all. One of the places where Chile is a leader in market design is school choice: how people are assigned to schools and Chile has done a lot of work on this, although mainly for public schools.”

—What do you know about this system in Chile?

“Not long ago, before there was centralized and widespread school choice in Chile, there were the usual problems with decentralized school choice; That is, parents had to get up early to get in line, and they had a difficult process to register their children.”

—The new system has been criticized. Some claim it caused more people to choose the private system over the public school system. Isn't it similar to what is happening in New York, for example?

“There is something to that. In New York and Boston we also have a system that we call charter schools: free access schools, but organized by private entities, even if they are municipal schools. And they also have different standards. School choice is important, but it does not solve the problems of poverty or income inequality. Now, one of the reasons we have school choice in the United States and perhaps also in Chile is because we think that, otherwise, there is a danger that the poor will be condemned to send their children to poor schools. .

—Has there been any successful case in which parents can honestly rank the order of preference for the school they want their children to go to?

“In Chile, procedures are used that [make it] what game  theorists call a dominant strategy to express true preferences. The [remaining] problem is not in creating systems that make it safe to express preferences, but in distributing the information so that people can form preferences sensibly. In the United States, the hardest families to reach are those who don't speak English at home, so it's sometimes difficult to communicate with them. And different families have different feelings about what kind of schools their children should attend.”

“The benefits of school choice come from the fact that some schools may be high quality for some children but not for others, so we would like children to attend the schools that are best quality for them.”

On kidneys:

—You are famous for the proposal that allowed the “kidney exchange.” Years after the first experience, what do you see now in this type of market?

“Kidney exchange is working quite well in the US, but it works especially well for patients who are not too difficult to match. Even in the US, a fairly large country, we have patients who are so difficult to match that we have trouble finding a kidney for them.”

—And in other countries?

“Smaller countries, with 20 million inhabitants, like Chile, would benefit if we could make national borders not so important. When we look at transplants per million inhabitants, Chile is in the middle of the world. But since it is a small country, when the total number of transplants performed is analyzed, Chile has very few. Kidneys are obtained from both deceased and living donors. In Chile, as in much of the world, the majority of transplants come from deceased donors. Kidney exchange would allow more transplants to come from living donors ... “Twenty million is not enough, so it would be very good to see in South America an exchange of kidneys that can cross between countries, which is not so easy to do.”

Equality of exchange and the role of perceptions

“One of the things that worries people when talking about transplants is that [they think it might be] a medical process that exploits the poor. Of course, the thing about kidney exchange is that each pair of people gives one kidney and receives one kidney. It is very egalitarian. I think kidney exchange is a good place to combat this notion that transplantation is like trafficking,” he notes.

—Notions, perceptions are very important. Many people think of “exchange” as the exchange of securities in the stock market.

“That's right, but not every exchange involves money. One of the discussions about money in the world that is taking place in the European Union at the moment is about payment to blood plasma donors. In the EU, only Germany, Austria, the Czech Republic and Hungary pay blood plasma donors. And those are the only EU countries that have as much blood plasma as they need. The others have to import everything, and they do it from the United States. The United States is the Saudi Arabia of blood plasma (…) The World Health Organization says that plasma must be obtained in each country, and from unpaid donors. You have to be self-sufficient... an economist finds that a little funny. Blood is a matter of life and death. “When there is a pandemic, we do not tell countries that they must be self-sufficient [in vaccines].”

—When we talk about these exchanges of blood plasma and kidneys, school choice systems, we are talking about the same idea: coincident or paired markets. But the concept of the market has been so questioned, especially by some political groups, for so long...

"It's true. Now,  kidney exchange is special because money doesn't change hands. Money changes hands to get medical care, you have to pay doctors, nurses and hospitals. But we are not talking about buying kidneys from donors, but rather that, at the patient level, each pair receives a kidney and donates a kidney. It is radically egalitarian. Many people who think about markets may not think of it as a market, but I think that's a mistake. Many markets are not just about money… we would worry much less about markets if income and wealth inequality did not exist. “What worries us about markets is that some people are poor and some people are rich, and markets seem like a way to give the rich an advantage.”

“There is no doubt that being rich is better than being poor. The real question is what do we do to alleviate poverty. Making it invisible is not the same as alleviating it. One of the reasons I think many countries don't allow blood and plasma donors to be paid is because they don't like the way that looks. It reminds them that some people would like to get some money and would donate blood for it.”







Apparently, according to the caption, I'm "affable and smiling" (although not in this picture:)

I was in Chile to participate in what turned out to be a wonderful workshop on market design at the University of Chile, organized by Itai Ashlagi, José Correa, and Juan Escobar.
#########
Update (Dec. 27): Here's an account of my closing public talk from the U. Chile's Center for Mathematical Modeling, one of the hosts of the market design workshop.

And here's a picture at the close, including some of those mentioned above: At my far left in the picture is José Correa,  who in addition to his other roles is Vice Rector for Information Technologies. Next to him is Alejandra Mizala, prorrector (provost) of the university.  Next to her (immediately to my left) is Rector of the University of Chile, Rosa Devés, and immediately to my right is market designer and director of the MIPP Millennium Institute, Juan Escobar. Next to him is Héctor Ramírez, director of the Center for Mathematical Modeling. And next to him (at my far right) is professor Rafael Epstein who (along with Correa, Escobar, and his daughter Natalie Epstein) has been involved with school choice in Chile, among other things.



Thursday, November 16, 2023

Top trading cycles 'respect improvements' by rewarding agents whose endowments become more desirable

 Here's a wide-ranging paper that explores the way the Top Tradinig Cycles (TTC) algorithm 'respects improvements' by rewarding an agent whose endowment becomes more desirable.

Biró, Péter, Flip Klijn, Xenia Klimentova, and Ana Viana. "Shapley–Scarf Housing Markets: Respecting Improvement, Integer Programming, and Kidney Exchange." Mathematics of Operations Research (2023).

"Abstract: In a housing market of Shapley and Scarf, each agent is endowed with one indivisible object and has preferences over all objects. An allocation of the objects is in the (strong) core if there exists no (weakly) blocking coalition. We show that, for strict preferences, the unique strong core allocation “respects improvement”—if an agent’s object becomes more desirable for some other agents, then the agent’s allotment in the unique strong core allocation weakly improves. We extend this result to weak preferences for both the strong core (conditional on nonemptiness) and the set of competitive allocations (using probabilistic allocations and stochastic dominance). There are no counterparts of the latter two results in the two-sided matching literature. We provide examples to show how our results break down when there is a bound on the length of exchange cycles. Respecting improvements is an important property for applications of the housing markets model, such as kidney exchange: it incentivizes each patient to bring the best possible set of donors to the market. We conduct computer simulations using markets that resemble the pools of kidney exchange programs. We compare the game-theoretical solutions with current techniques (maximum size and maximum weight allocations) in terms of violations of the respecting improvement property. We find that game-theoretical solutions fare much better at respecting improvements even when exchange cycles are bounded, and they do so at a low efficiency cost. As a stepping stone for our simulations, we provide novel integer programming formulations for computing core, competitive, and strong core allocations."

Here is their literature review:

"The nonemptiness of the core is proved in Shapley and Scarf [47] by showing the balancedness of the corresponding nontransferable utility game and also in a constructive way by showing that David Gale’s famous top trading cycles (TTC) algorithm always yields competitive allocations. Roth and Postlewaite [40] later show that, for strict preferences, the TTC results in the unique strong core allocation, which coincides with the unique competitive allocation in this case. However, if preferences are not strict (i.e., ties are present), the strong core can be empty or contain more than one allocation, but the TTC still produces all competitive allocations. Wako [50] shows that the strong core is always a subset of the set of competitive allocations. Quint and Wako [39] provide an efficient algorithm for finding a strong core allocation whenever there exists one. Their work is further generalized and simplified by Cechlárová and Fleiner [19], who use graph models. Wako [52] shows that the set of competitive allocations coincides with the core based on an antisymmetric weak domination concept, which we refer to as Wako-core in this paper. This equivalence is key for our extension of the definition of competitive allocations to the case of bounded exchange cycles.

1.2.2. Respecting Improvement.

"For Gale and Shapley’s [23] college admissions model, Balinski and Sönmez [11] prove that SOSM respects improvement of student’s quality. Kominers [29] generalizes this result to more general settings. Balinski and Sönmez [11] also show that SOSM is the unique stable mechanism that respects improvement of student quality. Abdulkadiroğlu and Sönmez [3] propose and discuss the use of TTC in a model of school choice, which is closely related to the college admissions model. Abdulkadiroğlu and Che [2] state and Hatfield et al. [25] formally prove that the TTC mechanism respects improvement of student quality.

"Hatfield et al. [25] also focus on the other side of the market and study the existence of mechanisms that respect improvement of a college’s quality. The fact that colleges can match with multiple students leads to a strong impossibility result: they prove that there is no stable or Pareto-efficient mechanism that respects improvement of a college’s quality. In particular, the (Pareto-efficient) TTC mechanism does not respect improvement of a college’s quality.

"In the context of KEPs with pairwise exchanges, the incentives for bringing an additional donor to the exchange pool was first studied by Roth et al. [42]. In the model of housing markets their donor-monotonicity property boils down to the respecting improvement property. They show that so-called priority mechanisms are donor-monotonic if each agent’s preferences are dichotomous, that is, the agent is indifferent between all acceptable donors. However, if agents have nondichotomous preferences, then any mechanism that maximizes the number of pairwise exchanges (so, in particular, any priority mechanism) does not respect improvement. This can be easily seen by means of Example 4 in Section 3.3.

#######

See also

The core of housing markets from an agent’s perspective: Is it worth sprucing up your home?  by Ildiko Schlotter, , Peter Biro, and Tamas Fleiner

Abstract. We study housing markets as introduced by Shapley and Scarf (1974). We investigate the computational complexity of various questions regarding the situation of an agent a in a housing market Hwe show that it is NP-hard to find an allocation in the core of H where (i) a receives a certain house, (ii) a does not receive a certain house, or (iii) a receives a house other than her own. We prove that the core of housing markets respects improvement in the following sense: given an allocation in the core of H where agent a receives a house h, if the value of the house owned by a increases, then the resulting housing market admits an allocation in its core in which a receives either h or a house that a prefers to h; moreover, such an allocation can be found efficiently. We further show an analogous result in the Stable Roommates setting by proving that stable matchings in a one-sided market also respect improvement.


Saturday, September 16, 2023

NBER Market Design Working Group Meeting, Fall 2023, Cambridge MA

 Market Design Working Group Meeting, Fall 2023

Friday, October 27

8:30 am
9:00 am
9:45 am
10:30 am
10:45 am
11:30 am
12:15 pm
1:30 pm
2:15 pm
3:00 pm
3:45 pm
4:15 pm
5:00 pm
5:45 pm
6:30 pm

Saturday, October 28

8:30 am
9:00 am
9:45 am
10:30 am
11:00 am
11:45 am
12:30 pm
1:30 pm
2:15 pm
3:00 pm


Thursday, September 7, 2023

Navigating NYC school choice: advice for families

 Each year a new cohort of families has to navigate school choice in New York City.  The city offers lots of resources for gathering information.  One advantage of employing methods that make it safe to reveal true preference orders is that at least one aspect of the process is straightforward. (Of course, constructing a list of 12 schools out of the many available isn't easy.)

The NY Times offers a guide, which is full of information on how to go about gathering information with which to form preferences over schools:

Applying to N.Y.C. Public Schools Can Feel Daunting. Here’s What to Know. What matters when choosing a school? How should you compare options? And what’s the best strategy for getting your first choice?  By Troy Closson, Sept. 5, 2023,

"What’s the best strategy when applying?

"You should rank schools and programs in order of your true preference. There is no better approach. Students are considered for a lower choice only if a higher ranked school does not have space.

"Admissions experts suggest creating a complete list of 12 schools with a balance of programs, priorities and demand per seat, which you can find on MySchools. Apply by the deadline; there is also no benefit to applying earlier"


HT: Parag Pathak

*******

Another resource:

Abdulkadiroglu, Atila , Parag A. Pathak, and Alvin E. Roth, "Strategy-proofness versus Efficiency in Matching with Indifferences: Redesigning the NYC High School Match,'' American Economic Review, 99, 5, Dec. 2009, pp1954-1978. 

Wednesday, August 30, 2023

Minimal envy mechanisms, by Julien Combe

 Here's an article I missed when it came out online:

Reallocation with priorities and minimal envy mechanisms, by Julien Combe, Economic Theory volume 76, 551–584 (2023)

"Abstract: We investigate the problem of reallocation with priorities where one has to assign objects or positions to individuals. Agents can have an initial ownership over an object. Each object has a priority ordering over the agents. In this framework, there is no mechanism that is both individually rational (IR) and stable, i.e. has no blocking pairs. Given this impossibility, an alternative approach is to compare mechanisms based on the blocking pairs they generate. A mechanism has minimal envy within a set of mechanisms if there is no other mechanism in the set that always leads to a set of blocking pairs included in the one of the former mechanism. Our main result shows that the modified Deferred Acceptance mechanism (Guillen and Kesten in Int Econ Rev 53(3):1027–1046, 2012), is a minimal envy mechanism in the set of IR and strategy-proof mechanisms. We also show that an extension of the Top Trading Cycle (Karakaya et al. in J Econ Theory 184:104948, 2019) mechanism is a minimal envy mechanism in the set of IR, strategy-proof and Pareto-efficient mechanisms. These two results extend the existing ones in school choice."

Monday, August 28, 2023

Unclaimed bodies and medical school anatomy classes.

 There's a long history of unclaimed bodies being used in medical school anatomy classes. (I think the historical availability of such cadavers is one of the reasons that the Harvard Medical School is in Boston rather than Cambridge.*)  Here's an update on the practice, in Texas.

Unclaimed Bodies and Medical Education in Texas, by Eli Shupe, PhD1; Serena Karim2; Daniel Sledge, PhD, JAMA.  online August 24, 2023

"The use of unclaimed bodies (bodies not claimed by next of kin for burial or cremation) in gross anatomy education in the US has declined substantially since the middle of the 20th century owing to increases in voluntary donations and escalating ethical concerns.1-3 Nonetheless, in most US jurisdictions, counties can donate unclaimed bodies to science without consent from the deceased or their next of kin, with some medical schools still accepting such donations. The current scope and magnitude of the use of unclaimed bodies in the US is underresearched, although one 2019 study found that anatomy course leaders at 12.4% of surveyed US medical schools indicated possible use of unclaimed bodies at their institutions.4 The objective of this study was to examine the trends in use of unclaimed bodies in medical education in Texas.

...

"We found that during 2017-2021, 6 of the 14 medical schools in our sample (42.9%) either engaged in the direct procurement and use of unclaimed bodies (2 schools, 14.3%) or received transferred cadavers from schools that did (4 schools, 28.6%). The remaining 8 schools (57.1%) had no possible use of unclaimed bodies."

###########

*Here's a related story from the Harvard Crimson:

Harvard's Habeas Corpus: Grave Robbing at Harvard Medical School, BY NURIYA SAIFULINA, September 28, 2017

"Harvard’s corpse legacy began in late 18th century, when the newly opened Medical School began hiring grave diggers—not to bury bodies, but to exhume them. According to a 2015 history of the so-called “resurrection men” in Synthesis, an undergraduate history of science journal, the diggers snuck into Boston’s burial grounds in search of new graves, stealthily dug up some of the most “fresh” residents, and refilled the graves to avoid arousing suspicion.

...

"Around 1770, Joseph Warren founded an illicit secret society called the “Spunker Club,” also known as the “Anatomical Club.” His older brother, John Warren—the founder of Harvard Medical School—was also a member. Some of the club’s most notable members included a William Eustis, the future governor of Massachusetts, and Samuel Adams’ son.

...

"As “resurrection men” and body-snatching enthusiasts continued to ransack Boston graveyards, civil indignation incited the Act to Protect the Sepulchers of the Dead in 1815, making disturbance of buried bodies illegal and prompting a citywide patrol of graveyards and burial grounds.

"This legislature forced Harvard Medical School to “import” the cadavers from New York instead, where body snatchers were “emptying at least six hundred or seven hundred graves annually,” according to an article in the Boston Gazette.

"After the Massachusetts Medical Society published a plea in 1829 claiming that medical students had no other choice but to pursue their studies “in defiance of the law of the land,” the school’s need for illegally-obtained cadavers waned. Massachusetts passed the Anatomy Act of 1831, which allowed for dissection of the unclaimed bodies of the indigent, insane and imprisoned."

Wednesday, August 9, 2023

SITE 2023 Session 5: Experimental Economics Thu, Aug 10 - Fri, Aug 11 2023

 SITE 2023 Session 5: Experimental Economics   Thu, Aug 10 2023, 9:00am - Fri, Aug 11 2023, 5:00pm PDT

John A. and Cynthia Fry Gunn Building, 366 Galvez Street, Stanford, CA 94305

ORGANIZED BY Christine Exley, Harvard University  Kirby Nielsen, California Institute of Technology  Muriel Niederle, Stanford University  Alvin Roth, Stanford University  Lise Vesterlund, University of Pittsburgh

This session will be dedicated to advances in experimental economics combining laboratory and field-experimental methodologies with theoretical and psychological insights on decision-making, strategic interaction and policy. We are inviting papers in lab experiments, field experiments and their combination that test theory, demonstrate the importance of psychological phenomena, and explore social and policy issues. In addition to senior faculty members, invited presenters will include junior faculty as well as graduate students.

Thursday, August 10, 2023

9:00 AM - 9:30 AM PDT  Breakfast and Welcome

AUG 10 9:30 AM - 10:00 AM PDT

Information Avoidance and Image Concerns

Presented by: Judd Kessler (The Wharton School)

Co-author(s): Christine L. Exley (Harvard University)

A rich literature finds that individuals avoid information and suggests that avoidance is driven by image concerns. This paper provides the first direct test of whether individuals avoid information because of image concerns. We build off of a classic paradigm, introducing control conditions that make minimal changes to eliminate the role of image concerns while keeping other key features of the environment unchanged. Data from 6,421 experimental subjects shows that image concerns play a role in driving information avoidance, but a role that is substantially smaller than one might have expected.


AUG 10 10:00 AM - 10:30 AM PDT

Transactional Preferences and the Minimum Wage

Presented by: Kristóf Madarász (London School of Economics)

Co-author(s): Anna Becker (Stockholm University), Attila Lindner (University College London), and Heather Sarsons (University of British Columbia)

A growing number of studies suggest that minimum wages have limited disemployment effects while at the same time increasing output prices. This finding contradicts the ”law of demand”, which states that output demand, and therefore employment, should fall whenever prices increase. We propose a simple framework to explain this fact and to highlight some aspects of ethical consumption more generally. Consumers derive extra utility when engaging in transactions that can be associated with positive moral attributes. In the context of the minimum wage, consumers derive a higher marginal utility when they know that the good they are consuming is produced by a worker earning a higher wage. Combined with firms’ inability to credibly commit to higher wages, a mandated minimum wage policy can lead to higher output and positive employment effects simultaneously. We implement an online survey experiment in the U.S. to test for the proposed mechanism. We use our findings to reassess the welfare implications of the policy.


AUG 10 10:30 AM - 11:00 AM PDT

Assessing Behavioral Incentive Compatibility

Presented by: Lise Vesterlund (University of Pittsburgh)

AUG 1011:00 AM - 11:30 AM PDT Break

AUG 10


11:30 AM - 12:00 PM PDT

Connecting Common Ratio and Common Consequence Preferences

Presented by: Charlie D. Sprenger (Caltech)

Co-author(s): Christina McGranaghan (University of Delaware), Kirby Nielsen (California Institute of Technology), Ted O’Donoghue (Cornell University), and Jason Somerville (Federal Reserve Bank of New York)

Many models of decision-making under uncertainty are motivated by two prominent deviations from expected utility (EU): the common consequence effect (CCE) and the common ratio effect (CRE). Both decision problems were originally proposed as thought experiments by Allais (1953), and later popularized by Kahneman & Tversky (1979). The apparent deviations from EU predictions in each problem have motivated a wide body of decision theories in risky choice.

Although the CRE and CCE both represent violations of the EU axiom of independence, they have been studied mostly independently, and using quite different experimental parameters. In fact, however, the two decision problems are closely related: If conducted at a common set of experimental parameters, the two problems would share three out of four possible options. Moreover, the connections between the two problems are relevant for assessing various non-EU models—i.e., different models predict specific patterns.

In this paper, we extend existing empirical tests by (i) explicitly recognizing the connection between the two decision problems; (ii) conducting a large number of experiments covering connected CRE and CCE problems at different experimental parameters; and (iii) implementing experiments using both paired choice tasks (for comparison to the prior literature) and paired valuation tasks (our preferred approach given the inferential challenges outlined in McGranaghan et al (2022)).

Our results provide important insights on the shape of risk preferences. We find small but significant CR preferences, but systematic reverse CC preferences. Through their connection, this pattern implies that individuals violate betweenness by preferring mixtures. These results are inconsistent with leading non-EU models, and we propose a model to rationalize these findings.


AUG 10  12:00 PM - 12:30 PM PDT

Beliefs in a High-Stakes Environment

Presented by: Stephanie Wang (University of Pittsburgh)

Co-author(s): Yiming Liu (Humboldt University of Berlin)

It has been well-documented that people tend to be overconfident. We investigate whether biased beliefs in performance persist in a high-stakes environment. Specifically, we ask whether students are overconfident when estimating their high school entrance exam performance. Students in our environment have strong incentives to accurately assess their exam scores because they need to submit their rank order list under an immediate acceptance mechanism before knowing their exam performance. Combining administrative and survey data on estimated performance and actual performance, we find no evidence for overconfidence in estimation in this high-stakes environment. However, when we remove the high stakes by eliciting students’ recall of their performance in a previous mock exam, they show a strong pattern of overconfidence. Consistent with Benabou and Tirole  ́ (2002)’s theory of the supply of biased beliefs through biased memory, we find suggestive evidence that students rely on their potentially biased memory of past performance to construct their high-stakes estimation.


AUG 11 12:30 PM - 2:0

AUG 10 12:30 PM - 2:00 PM PDT Lunch/Discussion

AUG 10 2:00 PM - 2:15 PM PDT

Procedural Decision-Making in the Face of Complexity

Presented by: Gonzalo Arrieta (Stanford University)

Co-author(s): Kirby Nielsen (California Institute of Technology)

Individuals often change their decision-making in response to complexity, as has been discussed for decades in psychology and economics, but existing literature provides little evidence on the general characteristics of these processes. We introduce an experimental methodology to show that in the face of complexity, individuals resort to “procedural” decision-making, which we categorize as choice processes that are more describable. We elicit accuracy in replicating decision-makers’ choices to experimentally measure and incentivize the choice process’ describability. We show that procedural decision-making increases as we exogenously vary the complexity of the environment, defined by the choice set’s cardinality. This allows for procedural reinterpretations of existing findings in decision-making under complexity, such as in the use of heuristics.


AUG 10 2:15 PM - 2:30 PM PDT

What Drives Violations of the Independence Axiom? The Role of Decision Confidence

Presented by: Aldo Lucia (California Institute of Technology)

Recent theoretical work implicates decision confidence as a central component of decision-making under uncertainty, attributing failures of Expected Utility (EU) to a lack of confidence. We design an experiment testing EU’ central independence axiom and contemporaneously eliciting measures of decision confidence. We find that choices characterized by high self-reported levels of decision confidence and low response times are more likely to com-ply with the independence axiom. Contrary to the common certainty effect rationale for independence violations, we show that subjects predominantly violate EU by choosing risky lotteries over certain amounts when they are unconfident in their choices.


AUG 10 2:30 PM - 2:45 PM PDT

Does Artificial Intelligence Help or Hurt Gender Diversity? Evidence from Two Field Experiments on Recruitment in Tech

Presented by: Mallory Avery (Monash University)

Co-author(s): Andreas Leibbrandt (Monash University) and Joseph Vecci (University of Gothenburg)

The use of Artificial Intelligence (AI) in recruitment is rapidly increasing and drastically changing how people apply to jobs and how applications are reviewed. In this paper, we use two field experiments to study how AI in recruitment impacts gender diversity in the male-dominated technology sector, both overall and separately for labor supply and demand. We find that the use of AI in recruitment changes the gender distribution of potential hires, in some cases more than doubling the fraction of top applicants that are women.This change is generated by better outcomes for women in both supply and demand. On the supply side, we observe that the use of AI reduces the gender gap in application completion rates. Complementary survey evidence suggests that this is driven by female jobseekers believing that there is less bias in recruitment when assessed by AI instead of human evaluators. On the demand side, we find that providing evaluators with applicants’ AI scores closes the gender gap in assessments that otherwise disadvantage female applicants. Finally, we show that the AI tool would have to be substantially biased against women to result in a lower level of gender diversity than found without AI.


AUG 10 2:45 PM - 3:00 PM PDT

Regulation of Organ Transplantation and Procurement: A Market Design Lab Experiment

Presented by: Alex Chan (Harvard University)

Co-author(s): Alvin E. Roth (Stanford University)

We conduct a lab experiment that shows current rules regulating transplant centers (TCs) and organ procurement organizations (OPOs) create perverse incentives that inefficiently reduce both organ recovery and beneficial transplantations. We model the decision environment with a 2-player multi period game between an OPO and a TC. In the condition that simulates current rules, OPOs recover only highest-quality kidneys and forgo valuable recovery opportunities, and TCs decline some beneficial transplants and perform some unnecessary transplants. Alternative regulations that reward TCs and OPOs together for health outcomes in their entire patient pool lead to behaviors that increase organ recovery and appropriate transplants.


AUG 10 3:00 PM - 3:30 PM PDT Break

AUG 10 3:30 PM - 3:45 PM PDT

Memory and the Persistence of Gender Discrimination

Presented by: Francesca Miserocchi (Harvard University)

Standard models of discrimination assume that decision-makers use all the available information about candidates when making their decisions. Based on research in psychology, I test the hypothesis that when decision-makers have a lot of other information in their mind, they are less likely to remember how particular individuals performed and fall back on stereotypes, which disadvantages women in predominantly male-dominated fields. First, in years when teachers need to evaluate a larger number of students – amplifying memory constraints – girls are considerably less likely to be recommended for top-tier scientific high school tracks. On the contrary, the gender gap in students’ objective math ability does not expand during these years. Second, I conduct an experiment in which teachers assign track recommendations for hypothetical student profiles. Teachers are less likely to recommend girls to scientific tracks if they freely recall the information about them than when they can reference the information (proxying a perfect memory benchmark). Third, when asked to remember a candidate’s past performance on a series of trivia questions in sports and pop-culture, participants tend to remember a higher share of correct sports questions when they are answered by a boy than by an identical girl. The opposite is true for pop-culture questions. The results suggest that a significant portion of gender discrimination is driven by imperfect and selective memory of previously observed information, opening up the scope for policy interventions in the form of structured reminders.


AUG 10  3:45 PM - 4:00 PM PDT

Revealed Preference when Attention is Selective and Malleable

Presented by: John Conlon (Stanford University)

I show experimentally that information persuades not only by shifting beliefs but also by redirecting attention. Participants in my experiment decide whether to purchase a multi-attribute good. At baseline, selective attention generates large distortions in how responsive demand is to the values of these attributes. Randomly providing information about the value of one attribute, even when it is already known and transparently redundant, starkly increases responsiveness to that attribute and distracts attention from others. These forces can produce paradoxical responses to correcting beliefs: reducing overoptimism about an attribute can nonetheless boost demand for its associated good. 


AUG 10  4:00 PM - 4:15 PM PDT

Interventionist Preferences and the Welfare state: The Case of In-Kind Nutrition Assistance

Presented by: Tony Q. Fan (Stanford University)

Co-author(s): Sandro Ambuehl (University of Zurich), B. Douglas Bernheim (Stanford University), and Zach Freitas-Groff (Stanford University)

Poverty assistance is often administered in-kind even though cash transfers might raise recipients’ welfare more effectively. We characterize the political economy constraint that paternalistic motives impose on the welfare system. In our experiment, a representative sample of U.S. citizens reveal their motives by deciding whether to constrain real U.S. food stamp recipients’ choices between in-kind donations and cash equivalents we disburse. The modal respondent (40%) imposes the strictest possible constraints, while 30% impose no constraints. Hence, the majority’s behavior is consistent with deontological motives rather than trade-off thinking. Yet, because of biased beliefs about recipient preferences, respondents underestimate the restrictiveness of their interventions, suggesting that they are partly misguided. Overall, respondents’ goal is not to ensure sufficient healthy nutrition, but to prevent consumption of items deemed inappropriate. While respondents reveal racial and gender stereotypes in various survey questions, neither donor nor recipient demographics have substantial effects on restriction decisions, though restrictions increase with respondents’ political conservatism. In-experiment behavior correlates strongly with views about government policy.


AUG 10  5:00 PM - 8:00 PM PDT  Dinner at Muriel’s House


Friday, August 11, 2023

9:00 AM - 9:30 AM PDT Breakfast and Welcome

AUG 11 9:30 AM - 10:00 AM PDT

Sleep: Educational Impact and Habit Formation

Presented by: Silvia Saccardo (Carnegie Mellon University)

Co-author(s): Osea Giuntella (University of Pittsburgh) and Sally Sadoff (University of California San Diego)

In a field experiment among undergraduates, we test the impact of interventions to increase sleep on sleep habits and academic achievement. Offering incentives contingent on sleeping at least 7 hours per night increases sleep during both the four-week treatment period and the one to five-week post-treatment period. The intervention also significantly increases GPA at the end of the semester. Our estimates suggest that causally increasing sleep by an average of 6 - 16 minutes per night improves GPA by 0.12 - 0.14 standard deviations. We additionally examine the role of timing of rewards and reminders and feedback for improving sleep habits. We find that immediate incentives combined with reminders and feedback have the largest impact during treatment, but do not outperform delayed incentives or reminders and feedback alone during the post-intervention period. Our results suggest that interventions targeting sleep are a cost-effective tool for improving educational outcomes.


AUG 11 10:00 AM - 10:30 AM PDT

Describing Deferred Acceptance to Participants: Experimental Analysis

Presented by: Ori Heffetz (Cornell University and Hebrew University)

Co-author(s): Yannai Gonczarowski (Harvard University), Guy Ishai (Hebrew University of Jerusalem), and Clayton Thomas (Princeton University)

Designed markets often rely on carefully crafted descriptions of mechanisms. By and large, these descriptions attempt to convey as directly as possible what the outcome of the market will be. Are there principled, alternative theories of how to construct descriptions to expose different properties of mechanisms? Recently-proposed menu descriptions aim to provide such a theory towards exposing the strategyproofness of real-world mechanisms such as Deferred Acceptance. We design an incentivized experiment to test the ability of a menu description of Deferred Acceptance (compared to a traditional description) to affect participant behavior and their understanding of strategyproofness. We also design treatments conveying the definition of strategyproofness itself rather than the full details of the mechanism, with one treatment inspired by traditional definitions and one inspired by menu descriptions.


AUG 11  10:30 AM - 11:00 AM PDT

Decomposing the Winner’s Curse in Common-Value Auctions: What is the Role of Contingent Thinking?

Presented by: Muriel Niederle (Stanford University)

AUG 11  11:00 AM - 11:30 AM PDT  Break

AUG 11  11:30 AM - 12:00 PM PDT

Stochastic Dominance and Preference for Randomization

Presented by: Séverine Toussaert (University of Oxford)

Decision theorists usually take a normative view on stochastic dominance: a decision maker who chooses a lottery that puts more weight on options he likes less must be making a mistake. In this paper, I argue that stochastic dominance violations may naturally occur in situations where anticipatory utility is high, such as going on a holiday trip. In such a situation, the decision maker may trade the certainty of going to his favorite destination for the excitement of not knowing where he will go. To document this phenomenon, I conduct an experiment in which participants make a series of binary choices between a sure destination and a lottery over holiday trips. The outcome of the lottery is revealed close to the date of travel. I vary the characteristics of the lotteries to understand when violations of stochastic dominance are most likely to occur and analyze their properties. I discuss the implications for the modelling of anticipatory utility.


AUG 11  12:00 PM - 12:30 PM PDT

Insensitive Investors

Presented by: Cary Frydman (University of Southern California)

Co-author(s): Constantin Charles (University of Southern California) and Mete Kilic (University of Southern California)

We experimentally study the transmission of subjective expectations into actions. Subjects in our experiment report valuations that are far too insensitive to their expectations, relative to the prediction from a frictionless model. We propose that the insensitivity is driven by a noisy cognitive process that prevents subjects from precisely computing asset valuations. The empirical link between subjective expectations and actions becomes stronger as subjective expectations approach rational expectations. Our results highlight the importance of incorporating weak transmission into belief-based asset pricing models. Finally, we discuss how cognitive noise can provide a microfoundation for inelastic demand in the stock market.


0 PM PDT  Lunch/Discussion

AUG 11  

2:00 PM - 2:30 PM PDT

The Experimenters' Dilemma: Inferential Preferences over Populations

Presented by: Alistair Wilson (University of Pittsburgh)

Co-author(s): Luca Rigotti (University of Pittsburgh) and Neeraja Gupta (University of Richmond)

We examine the experimenter’s preferences over different populations using statistical power under a fixed budget as the stand-in for the researcher’s utility. We consider five populations commonly used in experiments by economists: undergraduate students at a physical location, undergraduate students in a virtual setting, Amazon MTurk "workers", a filtered MTurk subset from CloudResearch, and Prolific. Focusing on noise due to inattention, observation costs dominate the comparisons, with the larger online population samples superior to the smaller lab samples. However, once we factor in responsiveness to treatment, the lab samples have greater power than either MTurk or Prolific.


AUG 11  2:30 PM - 3:00 PM PDT  Break

AUG 11 3:00 PM - 3:30 PM PDT

Quantifying Lottery Choice Complexity

Presented by: Benjamin Enke (Harvard University)

Co-author(s): Cassidy Shubatt (Harvard University)

We develop indices of the objective and subjective complexity of lottery choice problems that can be computed for any standard dataset. These indices reflect which choice set features increase error rates and cognitive uncertainty in gauging expected values. Using these measures, we study behavioral responses to complexity across one million experimental decisions. In line with a model of heteroscedastic cognitive noise, complexity (i) makes choices more inconsistent and regressive to people’s prior; (ii) predicts when subjects accept unattractive gambles; and (iii) spuriously generates complexity aversion and small-stakes risk aversion. In structural estimations, complexity-dependent heteroscedasticity improves model fit considerably more than prospect theory does.


AUG 11 3:30 PM - 4:00 PM PDT

Competing Causal Interpretations: A Choice Experiment

Presented by: Sandro Ambuehl (University of Zurich)

Co-author(s): Heidi C. Thysen (Norwegian School of Economics)

A central factor when choosing an action is its causal effect on the outcome of interest. Yet, causal information is often lacking. People instead observe correlational or historical data, along with causal interpretations and action recommendations provided by experts who frequently disagree with each other. We use a laboratory experiment to study human choice in such settings. Roughly half of our subjects attempt to determine the fit of the causal interpretations to past data, as the literature on model persuasion assumes, and we outline the limits to their ability to do so. Half the subjects’ choices are co-determined by the interpretations’ promises of future payouts, as the literature on narrative competition assumes, or by the downside these choices entail if they are mistaken. Additionally, subjects commonly employ heuristics such as Occam’s razor, but they usually prefer more complex interpretations to more parsimonious ones. We also study the extent to which behavior is robust to framing and has out-of-sample predictive power, as well as the relation between subjects’ choices and their political attitudes and psychological characteristics. Finally, we will characterize the contexts in which subjects’ behavioral tendencies expose them to the greatest losses and render them most receptive to misleading interpretations.


AUG 11 4:00 PM - 4:30 PM PDT

Extracting Models From Data Sets: An Experiment Using Notes-to-Self

Presented by: Guillaume Fréchette (New York University)

Co-author(s): Emanuel Vespa (University of California, San Diego) and Sevgi Yuksel (University of California, Santa Barbara)

We report results from an experiment designed to study how people extract patterns from their observations. The novel experimental design asks subjects to organize different sets of observations (data) with the goal of making predictions in similar situations. We study whether the predictions subjects make in each environment are consistent with them using some “model” that posits specific statistical relationships between different variables. We find that the predictions of most subjects can be rationalized by some model. Importantly, we find the most commonly used model is the optimal one in that it maximizes prediction accuracy. Deviations from the optimal model often involve use of simpler models that fail to account for statistically relevant correlations in the data. Variation in the set of observations presented to subjects across environments allows us to test whether the way subjects learn from data display a key aspect of causal reasoning: identification of conditional independence between variables. While we find strong evidence for this, we also observe that failures of this increase with the noise in the data. Complemented with ancillary non-choice data that emerges as a by-product of our design, our results provide insights into how people form models of the world by studying data and how they use these models to make predictions.


AUG 11   5:00 PM - 7:00 PM PDT Dinner in Courtyard