Tuesday, August 8, 2023

Homelessness and fentanyl, in Oregon and California

 Both the criminal justice system and the harm reduction movement seem to be facing an intractable problem with fentanyl and homelessness.  (We lost the war on drugs, but surrender isn't working either.)

Here are two NYT stories, from Oregon and California.

The Struggle to Save Portland, Oregon. The city has long grappled with street homelessness and a shortage of housing. Now fentanyl has turned a perennial problem into a deadly crisis and a challenge to the city’s progressive identity.  By Michael Corkery

"This city of 635,000 ...  has long grappled with homelessness. But during the pandemic this perennial problem turned into an especially desperate and sometimes deadly crisis that is dividing Portland over how to fix it.

...

"In 2022, Portland experienced a spate of homicides and other violence involving homeless victims that rattled many in the community.

...

"The search for answers points in many directions — to city and county officials who allowed tents on the streets because the government had little to offer in the way of housing, to Oregon voters who backed decriminalizing hard drugs and to the unrest that rocked Portland in 2020 and left raw scars.

"But what has turbocharged the city’s troubles in recent years is fentanyl, the deadly synthetic drug, which has transformed long standing problems into a profound test of the Portland ethos.

"Outreach workers in Portland say rampant fentanyl use has coincided with the increasing turmoil among many homeless residents.

"Doctors who care for people living on the streets say fentanyl addiction is proving harder to treat than many other dependencies."

***********

Homeless Camps Are Being Cleared in California. What Happens Next? One of the state’s largest homeless encampments was recently shut down in Oakland, but that didn’t stop the problem of homelessness.  By Livia Albeck-Ripka

"The evictions have brought into sharp relief one of the most intractable challenges for American cities, particularly those in California. As homelessness has surged, more people have congregated in large encampments for some semblance of security and stability. But such sites are often unsanitary and dangerous, exhausting neighbors and the owners of nearby businesses.

"What happens after the closure of Wood Street and other camps in California will serve as the latest test of how effectively the state is addressing homelessness. Nearly half of the nation’s unsheltered population — those who sleep on the streets, in tents, in cars or in other places not intended for human habitation — resides in California, according to last year’s federal tally of homelessness. The state makes up about 12 percent of the country’s overall population.

"In California, Democratic leaders who previously tolerated homeless camps have lost their patience for the tent villages and blocks of trailers that proliferated during the pandemic.

"Governor Newsom has helped clear homeless camps himself and has told mayors he was trying to set an example. San Diego recently banned encampments on public property. And Karen Bass, the mayor of Los Angeles, has moved more than 14,000 homeless people into temporary housing since taking office in December, her office said last month.

...

"Community cabins and safe camping sites usually provide only temporary shelter, falling short of the permanent housing that is considered ideal. But they seem to be the best that California can do, with a severe housing shortage and high costs. Despite the state’s spending of more than $30 billion since 2019 on housing-related programs, the homeless population there has continued to grow.

“This is a very difficult population to serve, with very complex needs. And if we can bring someone inside even for a little bit, that’s a victory for that person,” said Jason Elliott, the deputy chief of staff for Governor Newsom. “We may not have permanent housing stick the first time, or the fourth time or the fifth time, but we’re going to keep trying.”

"According to a September audit of Oakland’s homelessness services, close to half of the people housed in community cabins ended up back on the street in the 2020-21 fiscal year."

***********

Earlier:

Friday, July 14, 2023

Monday, August 7, 2023

SITE 2023 Session 4: Psychology and Economics Tue, Aug 8 - Wed, Aug 9 2023

 SITE 2023 Session 4: Psychology and Economics   Tue, Aug 8 2023, 9:00am - Wed, Aug 9 2023, 5:00pm PDT    John A. and Cynthia Fry Gunn Building, 366 Galvez Street, Stanford, CA 94305

ORGANIZED BY B. Douglas Bernheim, Stanford University, John Beshears, Harvard University, Vincent Crawford, University of Oxford & University of California San Diego, David Laibson, Harvard University, Ulrike Malmendier, University of California Berkeley

This session brings together researchers working on issues at the intersection of psychology and economics. The segment will focus on evidence of and explanations for non-standard choice patterns, as well as the positive and normative implications of those patterns in a wide range of economic decision-making contexts, such as lifecycle consumption and savings, workplace productivity, health, and prosocial behavior. The presentations will frequently build upon insights from other disciplines, including psychology and sociology. Theoretical, empirical, and experimental studies will be included. 

Tuesday, August 8, 2023

9:00 AM - 9:30 AM PDT Check-in & Breakfast

AUG 8 9:30 AM - 10:00 AM PDT

Sophisticated Consumers with Inertia: Long-Term Implications from a Large-Scale Field Experiment

Presented by: Navdeep S. Sahni (Stanford University)

Co-author(s): Klaus M. Miller (HEC Paris) and Avner Strulov-Shlain (University of Chicago)

Using a randomized field experiment with a leading European newspaper, we study both the inertia anticipated by consumers and the actual inertia they experience. Our experiment among two million readers varies promotional subscription terms, including whether or not the contract automatically renews to a full-price subscription by default. By analyzing their subscription behavior over two years, we study how consumers respond to inertia-inducing subscription contracts in the short- and long-run. We find strong inertia. Half of the auto-renewal contract takers continue to a full-price subscription while rarely using it. At the same time, consumers preempt their future inertia; 24%-36% of potential subscribers avoid subscribing when offered an auto renewal promo. Further, offering an auto-renewal contract decreases the share of subscribers over the two years after the promo by 10%. Even though auto-renewal generates higher revenue in the medium-run due to payments from inert subscribers, auto-renewal and auto-cancel are revenue equivalent after one year, but with fewer subscribers in auto-renewal. Using a mixed-types model, we estimate that while 70% of consumers are inert, a large majority of them (at least 58%) are aware of their inertia. Our results highlight the importance of sophistication about future biases in the market; sophisticated consumers avoid exploitation and are missed by researchers and firms analyzing only takers, since takers are selected on their na ̈ıvet ́e.


AUG 8  10:00 AM - 10:30 AM PDT

Hedging by Giving: Spiritual Insurance and Religious Donations

Presented by: Yu Zhang (Peking University)

Co-author(s): Yu-Jane Liu (Peking University), Juanjuan Meng (Peking University), and Dalin Sheng (Southwestern University of Finance and Economics)

This paper analyzes donation behaviors from the perspective of religious beliefs. Using a transaction-level dataset from an Asian economy, we show that higher income uncertainty predicts more donations, especially for religious donations, and after negative income uncertainty and health shock. This pattern is inconsistent with existing explanations of donation, but can be explained by a “spiritual insurance” channel, whereby donators believe that giving reduces the probability of the bad state. Indeed, we find that those who donate to non-local religious organizations reduce their insurance purchases, suggesting that “spiritual insurance” channel can be influential for donation and the insurance market.


AUG 8 10:30 AM - 11:00 AM PDT

The Creativity Premium: Exploring the Link Between Childhood Creativity and Life Outcomes

Presented by: Victoria Prowse (Purdue University)

Co-author(s): David Gill (Purdue University)

Success in life increasingly depends on key skills that allow people to thrive in education, the labor market, and their interactions with others. In this paper, we emphasize creativity as a key skill that is essential to open-ended problem solving and resistant to automation. We use rich longitudinal data to study the relationship between people’s creativity measured in childhood and their individual attributes and life outcomes. We find that childhood creativity predicts labor market and educational success: more creative individuals earn more during the course of their careers, work in higher occupational categories, and reach higher levels of educational attainment. Our analysis of attributes further suggests that creative individuals have a package of practical skills that allows them to thrive in work environments where learning from experience is important. We combine insights from our findings with evidence from psychology to propose creativity-improving interventions that could lead to substantial economic benefits.


AUG 8  11:00 AM - 11:30 AM PDT Break

AUG 8 11:30 AM - 12:00 PM PDT

The Dynamics of Networks and Homophily

Presented by: Leeat Yariv (Princeton University)

Co-author(s): Matthew O. Jackson (Stanford University), Stephen M. Nei (University of Exeter), and Erik Snowberg (University of Utah)

We examine friendships and study partnerships among university students over several years. At the aggregate level, connections increase over time, but homophily on gender and ethnicity is relatively constant across time, university residences, and different network layers. At the individual level, homophilous tendencies are persistent across time and network layers. Furthermore, we see assortativity in homophilous tendencies. There is weaker, albeit significant, homophily over malleable characteristics---risk preferences, altruism, study habits, and so on. We find little evidence of assimilation over those characteristics. We also document the nuanced impact of network connections on changes in Grade Point Average.


AUG 8 12:00 PM - 12:30 PM PDT

Strategic Behavior with Tight, Loose and Polarized Norms

Presented by: Eugen Dimant (University of Pennsylvania)

Co-author(s): Michele Gelfand (University of Maryland), Anna Hochleitner (University of Nottingham), and Silvia Sonderegger (University of Nottingham)

Descriptive norms - the behavior of other individuals in one's reference group - play a key role in shaping individual decisions. Organizations are increasingly using information about descriptive norms to nudge positive behavior change. When characterizing peer decisions, a standard approach in the literature is to focus on average behavior. In this paper, we argue both theoretically and empirically that not only averages but also the shape of the whole distribution of behavior can play a crucial role in how people react to descriptive norms. Using a representative sample of the U.S. population, we experimentally investigate how individuals react to strategic environments that are characterized by different distributions of behavior, focusing on the distinction between tight (i.e., characterized by low behavioral variance), loose (i.e., characterized by high behavioral variance), and polarized (i.e., characterized by u-shaped behavior) environments. We find that individuals indeed strongly respond to differences in the variance and shape of the descriptive norm they are facing: loose norms generate greater behavioral variance and polarization generates polarized responses. In polarized environments, most individuals prefer extreme actions -- which expose them to considerable strategic risk -- to intermediate actions that minimize such risk. Furthermore, in polarized and loose environments, personal traits and values play a larger role in determining actual behavior. This provides important insights into how individuals navigate environments that contain strategic uncertainty.


 AUG 8 12:30 PM - 2:00 PM PDT Lunch

AUG 8 2:00 PM - 2:30 PM PDT

Empathy, Motivated Reasoning, And Redistribution

Presented by: Tingyan Jia (Stanford University)

I investigate both theoretically and experimentally the economics of empathy and its implications for redistribution. I first define empathy as an accurate simulation of how one would feel if they were in another’s position, distinguishing it from altruism.I propose a novel mechanism by which personal experience affects distributional motives through empathy: wealthy individuals have selfish motivation not to be empathetic towards the poor in order to justify less redistribution; in addition, more varied personal experience of consumption constrains such motivated reasoning, therefore increasing empathy and redistribution. I provide a test of the mechanism in a laboratory setting. I create exogenous variation in experiences and manipulate the timing of information to identify the role of motivated reasoning for subjects with different experiences. I find strong support for the validity of the mechanism: subjects with uniform experience are more susceptible to self-serving motivated reasoning in both their empathy beliefs and redistribution choices.


AUG 8 2:30 PM - 3:00 PM PDT

CEO Social Preferences and Layoffs

Presented by: Marius Guenzel (The Wharton School)

Co-author(s): Clint Hamilton (University of California, Berkeley), and Ulrike Malmendier (University of California, Berkeley)

We study whether CEO social preferences influence firm decision-making with respect to employees, using a new dataset on layoff announcements by U.S. public firms. We first document sizable frictions in firms’ layoff decisions: after exogenous CEO changes, new CEOs make more, and shareholder value-increasing, layoffs. Consistent with a mechanism of social preferences arising through social interactions, CEOs become more reluctant to make layoffs over their tenure as they form more connections inside the firm. This effect is amplified for “difficult-to-implement” layoffs during recessions, near company headquarters, and during the holiday season. Finally, we document a personal cost of firing for CEOs in the form of accelerated long-run mortality.


AUG 8 3:00 PM - 3:30 PM PDT

Understanding Markets with Socially Responsible Consumers

Presented by: Botond Koszegi (Central European University)

Co-author(s): Marc Kaufmann (Central European University)

Many consumers care about climate change and other broad externalities. We model and analyze the market behavior of such “socially responsible consumers,” derive properties of the resulting competitive equilibria, and study the effectiveness of different policies. In violation of price taking, a vanishingly small consumer cares about her impact on the behavior of the rest of the market to a non-vanishing extent. That impact on others endogenously dampens the consumer’s direct effect on the externality, undermining responsible behavior. Dampening implies that even if all consumers value the externality like the social planner, they mitigate too little in any equilibrium, and may coordinate on the worst of multiple equilibria. To motivate consumers to lower the externality in a closed economy, a unit tax is superior to a cap-and-trade system, but there are policies that are better than a tax. Furthermore, under trade with a large or very polluting partner, a cap is better than a tax. When there are two products that are perfect substitutes in consumption but generate different externalities, there is always an equilibrium in which the products have the same price and consumers are indifferent between them. Under conditions we identify, this selfish equilibrium is the unique equilibrium. In a selfish equilibrium, a cap and a unit tax on the dirty product can achieve the same outcomes. In non-selfish equilibria, a proportional subsidy on the clean product dominates both a unit tax and a cap.


AUG 8  3:30 PM - 4:00 PM PDT  Break

AUG 8  4:00 PM - 4:30 PM PDT

Complexity and Time

Presented by: Benjamin Enke (Harvard University)

Co-author(s): Thomas Graeber (Harvard University) and Ryan Oprea (University of California, Santa Barbara)

We provide experimental evidence that core intertemporal choice anomalies – including extreme short-run impatience, structural estimates of present bias, hyperbolicity and transitivity violations – are driven by complexity rather than time or risk preferences. First, all anomalies also arise in structurally similar atemporal deci-sion problems involving valuation of iteratively discounted (but immediately paid) rewards. These computational errors are strongly predictive of intertemporal decisions. Second, intertemporal choice anomalies are highly correlated with indices of complexity responses including cognitive uncertainty and choice inconsistency. We show that model misspecification resulting from ignoring behavioral responses to complexity severely inflates structural estimates of present bias.


AUG 8 4:30 PM - 5:00 PM PDT

Cognitive Imprecision and Stake-Dependent Risk Attitudes

Presented by: Michael Woodford (Columbia University)

Co-author(s): Ziang Li (Princeton University) and Mel Win Khaw (Microsoft)

In an experiment that elicits subjects' willingness to pay (WTP) for the outcome of a lottery, we confirm the fourfold pattern of risk attitudes described by Kahneman and Tversky. In addition, we document a systematic effect of stake sizes on the magnitude and sign of the relative risk premium, holding fixed both the probability that a lottery pays off and the sign of its payoff (gain vs. loss). We further show that in our data, there is a log-linear relationship between the monetary payoff of the lottery and WTP, conditional on the probability of the payoff and its sign. We account quantitatively for this relationship, and the way in which it varies with both the probability and sign of the lottery payoff, in a model in which all departures from risk-neutral bidding are attributed to an optimal adaptation of bidding behavior to the presence of cognitive noise. Moreover, the cognitive noise required by our hypothesis is consistent with patterns of bias and variability in judgments about numerical magnitudes and probabilities that have been observed in other contexts.


AUG 8  5:30 PM - 7:30 PM PDT Dinner


Wednesday, August 9, 2023  9:00 AM - 9:30 AM PDT Check-in & Breakfast

AUG 9 9:30 AM - 10:00 AM PDT

Paternalistic Discrimination

Presented by: Nina Caroline Buchmann (Stanford University)

Co-author(s): Carl Meyer (Stanford University) and Colin D. Sullivan (Purdue University)

Women in Bangladesh struggle to access the labor market in general and male-dominated occupations in particular, despite recent progress in education and training. We use a two-sided field experiment to identify paternalistic discrimination: the preferential hiring of male workers to protect female workers from jobs perceived as harmful or difficult. We observe real application and hiring decisions for a night-shift job in Bangladesh and experimentally vary employers’ and candidates’ perceptions of the danger of the job. Improvements to worker safety increase both the supply of and demand for female labor, leading to a compounding increase in female workers. In a behavioral labor model, we demonstrate how other-regarding preferences affect hiring and wages in equilibrium, and we complement the experimental results with survey data to i) analyze the effect of paternalistic discrimination on horizontal and vertical gender segregation in different industries, ii) estimate the degree to which paternalistic preferences restrict women’s labor potential and work readiness, and iii) identify policies that can increase women’s employment across different industries in Bangladesh.


AUG 9 10:00 AM - 10:30 AM PDT

A Memory Model of Belief Formation

Presented by: Maxim Bakhtin (Stanford University)

Co-author(s): Muriel Niederle (Stanford University) and Markus M. Mobius (Microsoft Research)

We model a rational individual who forms beliefs on demand by retrieving observations from the memory database. While she can retrieve data only randomly, she has access to an index that divides the data into two parts, for example, women and men. We show that three effects — importance, variability, and rarity — determine which group is retrieved more under the optimal strategy. Hence although the agent uses Bayes rule to form beliefs, she is biased towards her prior among groups she rationally retrieves fewer data points from. We show that the optimal use of the index leads to rational beliefs that are best described as persistent stereotypes.


AUG 9  10:30 AM - 11:00 AM PDT

Selective Memory Equilibrium

Presented by: Drew Fudenberg (Massachusetts Institute of Technology)

Co-author(s): Giacomo Lanzani (Massachusetts Institute of Technology) and Philipp Strack (Yale University)

We study agents who are more likely to remember some experiences than others, but update beliefs as if the experiences they remember are the only ones that occurred. If the agent’s behavior converges, their limit strategy is a selective memory equilibrium. We illustrate how selective memory equilibrium can be used to understand the long-run effects of several well-documented memory biases. We then extend our analysis to cases where the expected number of  recalled experiences is bounded and experiences that are recalled once are more likely to be recalled again. Here we characterize the long-run action frequencies that can arise.


AUG 9  11:00 AM - 11:30 AM PDT  Break

AUG 9  11:30 AM - 12:00 PM PDT

Context-dependent Perceptions and Decision Making

Presented by: Keyu Wu (University of Zürich)

All choices are based on information about the available options. A large body of research documents, however, that the same information is often perceived and evaluated differently depending on the prevailing context. Moreover, seemingly identical contextual information, such as previously seen products or job applicants, have been shown to exert opposing influences on perceptions of the same information about a “target” product or job applicant. Inspired by insights from neuroscience and psychophysics, I propose a unifying framework that can parsimoniously reconcile the seemingly contradictory influences of contextual information. This framework generates a novel set of predictions for how properties of the contextual information and the target, such as the perceived uncertainty in both and the perceived discrepancy between them, can be manipulated to affect perceptions and decisions. Because of the generality of perceptual regularities, the framework yields testable implications for a wide range of decision domains, such as the perceived attractiveness of products and services, the evaluation of job applicants, the perceived acceptability of wages, or the perceived trustworthiness of politicians. In addition, based on an experiment on risky investment decisions, I document how decisions can be changed as predicted by the framework through appropriately manipulating several properties of tthe context and the target.


AUG 9  

12:00 PM - 12:30 PM PDT

When Do “Nudges” Increase Welfare?

Presented by: Dmitry Taubinsky (University of California, Berkeley)

Co-author(s): Hunt Allcott (Stanford University), Daniel Cohen (Northwestern University), and William Morrison (University of California, Berkeley)

Policymakers are increasingly interested in non-standard policy instruments (NPIs), or “nudges,” such as simplified information disclosure and warning labels. We characterize the welfare effects of NPIs using public finance sufficient statistic approaches, allowing for endogenous prices, market power, and optimal or suboptimal taxes. While many empirical evaluations have focused on whether NPIs increase ostensibly beneficial behaviors on average, we show that this can be a poor guide to welfare. Welfare also depends on whether the NPI reduces the variance of distortions from heterogenous biases and externalities, and the average effect becomes irrelevant with zero pass-through or optimal taxes. We apply our framework to randomized experiments evaluating automotive fuel economy labels and sugary drink health labels. In both experiments, the labels increase ostensibly beneficial behaviors but also may decrease welfare in our model, because they increase the variance of distortions.


AUG 9  12:30 PM - 2:00 PM PDT  Lunch

AUG 9  2:00 PM - 2:30 PM PDT

Communicating with Anecdotes

Presented by: Nicole Immorlica (Microsoft Research)

Co-author(s): Nika Haghtalab (University of California, Berkeley), Brendan Lucier (Microsoft Research), Markus Mobius (Microsoft Research), and Divyarthi Mohan (Tel Aviv University)

We study a communication game between a sender and receiver where the sender has access to a set of informative signals about a state of the world. The sender chooses one of her signals and communicates it to the receiver. We call this an “anecdote.” The receiver takes an action. The state of the world and the receiver action are payoff relevant for both the sender and receiver. The sender and receiver are also influenced by a personal preference so that, fixing the state of the world, their preferred receiver action differs. We characterize perfect Bayesian equilibria of this game. The sender faces a temptation to persuade: she is tempted to select a more biased anecdote to influence the receiver’s action. Anecdotes are still informative to the receiver (who will debias at equilibrium) but the attempt to persuade comes at the cost of precision. This gives rise to “informational homophily” where the receiver prefers to listen to like minded senders because they provide higher-precision signals. Furthermore, this leads to a cost of informedness – fixing the personal preferences of the sender, the receiver may prefer a less-informed sender to a more-informed one for certain anecdote distributions.


AUG 9  2:30 PM - 3:00 PM PDT

Complexity, Communication and Misrepresentation

Presented by: Junya Zhou (Purdue University)

Co-author(s): Collin Raymond (Cornell University)

We investigate how increasing the complexity of the message space, in the presence of limited memory, can reduce misrepresentation in strategic communication. We enrich a standard cheap talk game so that senders must communicate not just a payoff-relevant state, but also payoff-irrelevant attributes correlated with the state. We show that: i) increasing the set of attributes that may need to be reported (i.e., the complexity of the game) improves the amount of information transmitted in equilibrium, ii) too much of an increase in complexity leads to a reversal of those gains, iii) limited memory on the part of players, as well as the relative complexity faced by senders and receivers, drives these changes, and iv) individuals experience cognitive costs when dealing with complex environments that they are willing to pay to avoid. Our findings demonstrate that the reporting of redundant information may induce equilibria that feature improved outcomes compared to simpler, more direct reporting systems, and point out the importance of complexity when trying to induce truthful information revelation.


AUG 9  3:00 PM - 3:30 PM PDT

Sequential Cursed Equilibrium

Presented by: Shengwu Li (Harvard University)

Co-author(s): Shani Cohen (Harvard University)

Cursed equilibrium posits that players in a Bayesian game neglect the relationship between their opponent’s actions and their opponent’s type (Eyster and Rabin, 2005). Sequential cursed equilibrium generalizes this idea to extensive games, including those with endogenous private information. It predicts that players neglect the information content of hypothetical events, but make correct inferences from observed events—as is consistent with data from experiments on hypothetical thinking.


AUG 9 3:30 PM - 4:00 PM PDT  Break

AUG 9  4:00 PM - 4:30 PM PDT

Evaluating the Evidence of Daily Income Targeting with Experimental and Observational Data

Presented by: Alec Brandon (Johns Hopkins University)

Co-author(s): Colin F. Camerer (California Institute of Technology), John A. List (University of Chicago), Ian Muir (Lyft, Inc.), and Jenny Wang (Massachusetts Institute of Technology)

We evaluate the evidence of daily income targeting by designing and analyzing a field experiment that randomly assigns financial windfalls across thousands of rideshare drivers. Over the year leading up to our windfall experiment, our sample replicates the observational finding that the faster a driver accumulates daily income the earlier they conclude their workdays. However, we find that our windfall treatment, which increases daily income by more than thirty percent, has no detectable effect on the labor supply of our sample. This null effect is estimated precisely enough to reject the effects predicted by the prior evidence and our replications. Heterogeneity analyses also fail to detect a statistically significant effect of the treatment windfall. Revisiting our replications, we find that a more complete measure of daily income and more flexible controls causes higher levels of daily income to no longer coincide with the early conclusion of workdays. The precision of our experimentally estimated nulls and the sensitivity of our replications to alternative specifications call into question much of the evidence of daily income targeting and provide guidance for future research.


AUG 9  4:30 PM - 5:00 PM PDT

Willingness to Accept, Willingness to Pay, and Loss Aversion

Presented by: Erik Snowberg (University of Utah)

Co-author(s): Colin Camerer (California Institute of Technology), Pietro Ortoleva (Princeton University), Mark Dean (Columbia University), and Jonathan Chapman (University of Bologna)

We use four incentivized representative surveys to study the endowment effect for lotteries in 4,000 U.S. adults. We replicate the standard finding of an endowment effect—the divergence between Willingness to Accept (WTA) and Willingness to Pay (WTP), but document three new findings. First, we find little evidence that the endowment effect is related to loss aversion for risky prospects, counter to predictions of popular theories in economics. Second, WTA and WTP not only diverge, but are, at best, weakly correlated. Third, WTA and WTP strongly relate to other aspects of risk preferences. The structure of these behaviors points to different theories of the endowment effect.


AUG 9 5:00 PM - 7:00 PM PDT Dinner

Sunday, August 6, 2023

Growing pains for legal marijuana, in California and beyond

The market for legal marijuana in the U.S. is suffering from (literal) growing pains, as large scale legal cultivation runs into both crop diseases, and zoning issues.

As a crop that is legal at the state level in many states, but still illegal under federal law, large cannabis farms don't get some of the benefits regarding the spread of plant diseases that are provided for other crops by the U.S. Department of Agriculture.

The WSJ has the story:

Cannabis Industry Confronts Billion-Dollar Threat: Weak Weed. Pathogen spreading among crops is cutting recreational drug’s potency, forcing growers to cull ‘dudded’ plants.  By Dean Seal

"A pathogen is contaminating cannabis crops around the country and threatening to leave billions of dollars of losses in its wake. 

"Cannabis researchers and experts are sounding the alarm for what is known as hop latent viroid, or HLVd, and cultivators are stepping up efforts to discover whether their plants are infected. The pathogen can drastically reduce the potency of the psychoactive compounds in marijuana, a phenomenon that growers have long called “dudding.”

...

"Plant pathologists and cannabis experts say the spread of the viroid was likely accelerated by the popularity of weed from California, which legalized cannabis for medical use in 1996.

"The spread also reflects the evolution of the cannabis business into a major agricultural crop. The risk of a new disease expanding increases for any crop that goes from low to high production, as cannabis has in the past two decades, said Jeremy Warren, Dark Heart’s director of plant science.

“You saw the spread happen in the legal states first, like California, where you started having bigger grows and bigger greenhouses that are making thousands and tens of thousands of plants,” Warren said. “In that system, it’s harder to maintain sanitation and it’s easier for a pathogen to take off.”

"The U.S. Agriculture Department typically sets quality standards and inspection requirements for agricultural products, but marijuana’s illegality at the federal level keeps it out of the agency’s purview."

*******

And big farms mean that agriculture and expensive housing may rub shoulders in California. Here's the Guardian on Santa Barbara County.

A beachside city became California’s legal cannabis capital. Not everyone is stoked  by Nicholas Schou

"Thanks to the most lenient policies in California for recreational marijuana, Santa Barbara county is now the state’s undisputed capital of legal cannabis, boasting more acres than the storied Emerald Triangle of Humboldt, Trinity and Mendocino counties.

"Santa Barbara voters overwhelmingly backed California’s legalisation of recreational marijuana in 2016, with hopes that the cannabis boom would bring tax revenue and new jobs to the county. The transformation has been fast and furious. Santa Barbara county is now home to around a third of all cultivation licenses issued in California, despite making up only 1.8% of the state’s land, with some megafarms stretching over dozens of acres.

"But the sudden influx of growers has inspired a broad coalition of frustration that spans local high schools, uber-wealthy homeowners and the region’s influential wine industry, who argue the pungent industry threatens to ruin their cherished lifestyle in a region dubbed the “American Riviera”.

...

"The tensions underscore a wider drama playing out in California over the promises of legal weed. Despite broad public support for bringing the industry out of the shadows, seven years on the illicit market is thriving, businesses are struggling to turn a profit, and many on the frontlines of the transition say they have yet to enjoy the returns.

"In fact, for the first time, officials in Santa Barbara are acknowledging that if market trends continue, the cost of the program both to public finances and to quality of life may outweigh any actual benefits.

...

"California’s cannabis market has been operating in a quasi-legal sphere since 1996, when medical marijuana was decriminalized. In 2016, advocates for Proposition 64 successfully argued that decriminalizing all cannabis use would create lucrative tax schemes and rewrite the historic injustices of policing such a widely used drug.

"But Prop 64 allowed cities to choose whether to allow cannabis businesses or not. Many refused to, banning both cultivation and dispensaries. Others, with varying degrees of success and scandal, sought to cash in on the “green rush”.

...

"Santa Barbara is alone among counties in that it taxes farmers based on the value of the marijuana they sell, as opposed to the acreage of their farms. While that strategy works when cannabis values are high, the industry has experienced a massive decline in profitability during the past year. With the sale price of cannabis in the state at roughly a third of its value just a year or so ago, many corporate investors have pulled out of the market entirely, and the number of licensed growers in Santa Barbara county has declined by about 25%.

"As a result, the county is expecting to earn just $7.5m in cannabis tax revenue this year, a 54% decline from 2022 and only half the $15.2m that was expected to fund the county’s latest budget, according to a county report."

Saturday, August 5, 2023

Prohibition, Moonshine, and the origins of stock car racing (NASCAR)

Prohibition (and before and after prohibition, high taxes) gave rise to black markets in alcohol. Some of the participants in those markets became folk heroes and later sports heroes, as smugglers became race car drivers, driving "stock" cars rather than cars that drew attention to themselves, eventually giving rise to the National Association for Stock Car Auto Racing (NASCAR).

Here's on old article from Smithsonian Magazine that gets right to the point:

How Moonshine Bootlegging Gave Rise to NASCAR. Rotgut and firewater are the founding fathers of our nation’s racing pastime.  by Jennifer Billock

"Even before Prohibition, erstwhile distillers were gathering in secret locations throughout rural areas in the south, brewing up homemade spirits to sell under the radar and away from alcohol taxes and bans. The drinks were made under the light of the moon, in hopes that no one would detect smoke rising from the stills and ultimately bust the operation—a practice that earned the booze its name “moonshine.”

"Moonshining dates back to the 1700s, when officials imposed taxes on liquor sales. Farmers and immigrants throughout the south took to making their own batches to sell for extra money, tax free, to counteract the effects of extreme poverty in the region. And with the introduction of Prohibition, production skyrocketed, creating a thriving black market business for secretly distilled hooch.

"Each hidden distillery needed to use runners—drivers in understated or otherwise ordinary-looking cars who could smuggle moonshine from the stills to thirsty customers across the region. On the outside, the cars looked “stock,” normal enough to avoid attention. But inside, both the mechanics of the cars and the drivers behind the wheel were far from ordinary. The vehicles were outfitted with heavy-duty shocks and springs, safeguarding the jars containing the hooch from breaking on bumpy mountain roads. The seats in the back were usually removed so more booze could fit. And high-powered engines gave the cars extra speed to outrun any cops and tax agents along the route. 

...

"From the 1930s on, once Prohibition had ended, demand for bootlegged alcohol waned and the runners found themselves with souped-up cars yet out of work—though they continued to take part in organized races. On December 14, 1947, one of these runners, Big Bill France, held a meeting with other drivers, car owners and mechanics to finally put in place some standardized rules for the races—thus NASCAR, the National Association for Stock Car Auto Racing, was born. The first official race was held two months later.

..."Arcadia Publishing released North Carolina Moonshine, a book about the Tar Heel State’s role in firewater history, covering everything from the NASCAR connection to local moonshining celebrities. In the book, the authors mention a secret garage hidden in the woods by the North Carolina-Virginia state line, which had opened in the 1930s and specialized in moonshine cars.

“This garage was operated for over 35 years by a shrewd, large and [purportedly] wily mechanic named Jelly Belly, who provided moonshine runners near and far with powerful cars that were almost untouchable,” authors Frank Stephenson Jr. and Barbara Nichols Mulder write."

*****

Moonshine whisky didn't completely disappear after the end of Prohibition, there are likely still some stills in the backcountry, to avoid taxes.  But while it's a tiny part of the whisky economy today, there are still auto sports heroes who got their start running the back roads with moonshine.  President Ronald Reagan pardoned one of them in 1985 for a 1956 conviction and prison sentence (followed by a storied racing career). The State of North Carolina commemorates the event here:

Junior Johnson Pardoned by Ronald Reagan

"On December 26, 1985, Robert Glen “Junior” Johnson received a  full and unconditional pardon from President Ronald Reagan for his 1956 conviction in federal court for moonshining.  Junior was caught firing up his father’s still and he became entangled in a barbed wire fence while trying to escape.  The conviction put Junior on a forced eleven-month, three-day hiatus in a federal penitentiary from his other career as a rising NASCAR star.

"Johnson, like many early NASCAR drivers, got his first high-speed driving experience in a souped-up automobile loaded with illegal white liquor.  He was a natural as a driver and has always made it a point of pride that the revenuers never caught him on the highway.  He parlayed his experience on the backroads of North Carolina into one of the most successful careers in NASCAR history.

********

Whisky running is memorialized in the NASCAR Hall of Fame:

DIGGING INTO NASCAR'S ROOTS, MOONSHINE RUNNERS & JUNIOR JOHNSON




HT: Kurt Sweat





Friday, August 4, 2023

AEA Guidance on the 2023-24 Economics Job Market Cycle

In an effort to forestall/halt/slow unravelling in the market for new Ph.D. economists, the American Economic Association has released some guidelines regarding interviews and offers.

 AEA Guidance on the 2023-24 Economics Job Market Cycle


July 27, 2023

To: Members of the American Economic Association and Economics Department Chairs
From: Peter L. Rousseau, Secretary-Treasurer
Subject: AEA Guidance on the 2023-24 Economics Job Market Cycle

AEA Guidance on the 2023-24 Economics Job Market Cycle

The AEA Executive Committee, in conjunction with its Committee on the Job Market, recognizes that it is to the benefit of the profession if the job market for economists is thick, with many employers and job candidates participating in the same stages at the same time.  Moreover, the AEA's goals of diversity, equity, and inclusion are fostered by having a timeline that remains widely known and accepted, ensuring that candidates can correctly anticipate when each stage will occur.  The AEA has a role to establish professional norms, which includes ensuring fair treatment of job candidates, including that they have enough time to consider job offers.

With these goals in mind, and in light of inquiries from both job candidates and employers about how to proceed, the AEA asks that departments and other employers consider the following timeline for initial interviews and “flyouts” in the upcoming job cycle (2023-24). 

Timing of interview invitations
The AEA suggests that employers wait to extend interview invitations until the day after job market signals are transmitted to employers (roughly December 1).

Rationale: the AEA created the signaling mechanism to reduce the problem of asymmetric information and allow job candidates to credibly signal their interest to two employers. The AEA asks that employers wait to extend interview invitations until those signals have been transmitted, and to use that information to finalize their set of candidates to interview. This helps the job market in several ways: it reduces the problem of imperfect information, it helps ensure a thick market at each stage, and it promotes the AEA’s goals of diversity, equity, and inclusion. Job candidates from historically under-represented groups may lack informal networks and thus may especially rely on the signals to convey their interest. Waiting to review the signals before issuing invitations promotes a fairer, more equitable process.

We also ask that all employers indicate on EconTrack when they have extended interview invitations. This allows candidates to learn about the status of searches without visiting websites posting crowd-sourced information and potentially inappropriate other content.

Timing of interviews
Initial interviews may take place any time after the AEA signals are sent (roughly December 1). The AEA recommends that all initial interviews take place virtually (e.g. by Zoom). We suggest that interviews not take place during the AEA meeting itself (January 5-7, 2024).

Rationale: In the past, interviews were conducted in-person at the AEA/ASSA meetings. This promoted thickness of the market, because most candidates and employers were present at the meetings, but had the disadvantage of precluding both job candidates and interviewers from fully participating in AEA/ASSA sessions. 

Initial job interviews went online during COVID, and feedback indicated that the benefits of virtual first-round interviews (e.g. low monetary cost, zero cost in travel time, scheduling flexibility, convenience) outweighed the limitations (e.g. less rich interaction).

We ask that interviews NOT take place during the AEA/ASSA meetings (January 5-7, 2024) in order to allow job candidates and interviewers to participate in the conference.

Timing of flyouts
Flyouts have historically happened at times appropriate for the employer, and the AEA sees no reason to suggest otherwise.  We ask that all employers indicate on EconTrack when they have extended flyout invitations. Unlike with interviews, the AEA does not take a position on whether flyouts should be virtual or in-person.

Timing of offers and “exploding” offers
In order to ensure that the job market remains sufficiently synchronized and thick, and that candidates have a chance to compare offers, the AEA recommends that employers leave job offers open (i.e. do not require candidates to accept or decline) until at least January 31.

The AEA also strongly recommends that employers give candidates at least two weeks to consider their job offer.  We recognize that offers made late in the job market season (e.g., March or later) may be of shorter duration.  In some circumstances, employers are under heavy pressure to give less time to candidates for various reasons.  If that is absolutely necessary, we recommend that employers give candidates a minimum of one week to consider the offer, and that candidates be given advance notice of this (e.g. at the flyout stage) whenever possible. 

Rationale: Recently, there is concern about a rise in “exploding offers” – i.e., offers for which candidates are given too few days to sufficiently consider the offer and their alternatives. This can prevent candidates from learning about their options or comparing offers, and at the extreme can be coercive.  Giving candidates two weeks (or, late in the job market season, at least one week) to consider an offer is a reasonable standard.

We also ask that all employers indicate on EconTrack when they have completed or closed their search.

Job market institutions and mechanisms
Please keep in mind the various job market institutions and mechanisms created by the AEA to improve the job market:

We encourage all employers to review and abide by Best Practices for Economists to Build a More Diverse, Inclusive, and Productive Profession, and in particular those for conducting a fair recruiting process.

Thank you for helping to ensure a transparent and equitable job market for new Ph.D. economists.  

Thursday, August 3, 2023

Market design conferences: Marseille, 11 – 15 December, and Santiago 18-20 December, 2023

 Here's the conference announcement from Marseille: 

From matchings to markets. A tale of Mathematics, Economics and Computer Science. Des matchings aux marchés. Une histoire de mathématiques. 11 – 15 December 2023, at the CIRM center in Marseille, France.

"This conference aims at gathering researchers from the fields of mathematics, computer science and economics (broadly defined) sharing common interests in the study of matching problems and the design of their markets. The presentations can cover a wide variety of topics and methods: specific matching markets, general models, theory, empirical analysis. . . etc"

Scientific Committee 
Comité scientifique 

Nick Arnosti (University of Minnesota)
Michal Feldman (Tel Aviv University)
Alfred Galichon (Science Po & New York University)
Michael Jordan (University of Stanford)
Claire Mathieu (CNRS – Collège France)

Organizing Committee
Comité d’organisation

Nick Arnosti (University of Minnesota)
Julien Combe (CREST & École Polytechnique)
Claire Mathieu (CNRS – Paris)
Vianney Perchet (ENSAE & Criteo AI lab)

*******
And here's the announcement of the conference in Santiago:

Keynote Speakers
Omar Besbes
Columbia University
Nicole Immorlica
Microsoft Research New England
Alvin Roth
Stanford University
Participants



Itai Ashlagi
Stanford University

Martin Castillo
New York University

Francisco Castro
University of California

José Correa
Universidad de Chile

Sofía Correa
Universidad de Chile

Andrés Cristi
Universidad de Chile

Juan Escobar
Universidad de Chile

Maximilien Ficht
Universidad de Chile

Yannai Gonczarowski
Harvard University

Nima Haghpanah
Pennsylvania State University

Jason Hartline
Northwestern University

Tibor Heumann
Pontificia Universidad Católica de Chile

Rahmi Ilkilic
Universidad de Chile

Revi Jagadeesan
Stanford University

Max Klimm
Technische Universität Berlin

Tomás Larroucau
Arizona State University

Mariana Laverde
Boston College

Ilan Lobel
New York University

Alfonso Montes
Universidad de Chile

Marcelo Olivares
Universidad de Chile

Renato Paes Leme
Google Research New York

Juan Sebastián Pereyra
Universidad de Montevideo

Adriana Piazza
Universidad de Chile

Dana Pizarro
Universidad de O'Higgins

Marco Scarsini
Universidad Luiss Guido Carli

Vasiliki Skreta
University of Texas at Austin

Laura Vargas-Koch
ETH Zurich

Víctor Verdugo
Universidad de O'Higgins

Matt Weinberg
Princeton University

Gabriel Weintraub
Stanford University

Asaf Zeevi
Columbia University